CAMPS NEWFOUND/OWATONNA, INC. v. TOWN OF HARRISON et al., (1997)
520 U.S. 564
Argued: October 9, 1996 Decided: May 19,
1997
Stevens, J., delivered the opinion of the Court,
in which O'Connor, Kennedy, Souter, and Breyer, JJ., joined. Scalia, J., filed
a dissenting opinion, in which Rehnquist, C. J., and Thomas and Ginsburg, JJ.,
joined. Thomas, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which Scalia, J., joined,
and in which Rehnquist, C. J., joined as to Part I.
The
question presented is whether an otherwise generally applicable state property
tax violates the Commerce Clause of the United States Constitution, Art. I, §
8, cl. 3, because its exemption for property owned by charitable institutions
excludes organizations operated principally for the benefit of nonresidents.
I
Petitioner
is a Maine nonprofit corporation that operates a summer camp for the benefit of
children of the Christian Science faith. The regimen at the camp includes
supervised prayer, meditation, and church services designed to help the
children grow spiritually and physically in accordance with the tenets of their
religion. App. 40-41. About 95 percent of the campers are not residents of
Maine. Id., at 44.
The camp is located in the town of Harrison (Town); it occupies 180
acres on the shores of a lake about 40 miles northwest of Portland. Brief for
Respondents 4, and n. 6. Petitioner's revenues include camper tuition averaging
about $400 per week for each student, contributions from private donors, and
income from a "modest endowment." App. 42, 51. In recent years, the
camp has had an annual operating deficit of approximately $175,000. Id., at
41. From 1989 to 1991, it paid over $20,000 in real estate and personal
property taxes each year.1 Id., at 42-43.
The Maine
statute at issue, Me. Rev. Stat. Ann., Tit. 36, § 652(1)(A) (Supp. 1996),
provides a general exemption from real estate and personal property taxes for
"benevolent and charitable institutions incorporated" in the State.
With respect to institutions that are "in fact conducted or operated
principally for the benefit of persons who are not residents of Maine,"
however, a charity may only qualify for a more limited tax benefit, and then
only if the weekly charge for services provided does not exceed $30 per person.
§ 652(1)(A)(1).2 Because most of the campers come from out of State,
petitioner could not qualify for a complete exemption.3 And, since
the weekly tuition was roughly $400, petitioner was ineligible for any
charitable tax exemption at all.
In 1992
petitioner made a formal request to the Town for a refund of taxes paid from
1989 through 1991, and a continuing exemption from future property taxes, based
principally on a claim that the tax exemption statute violated the Commerce
Clause of the Federal Constitution.4 The request was denied, and
petitioner filed suit in the Superior Court against the Town and its tax
assessors and collectors.5 After the parties agreed on the relevant
facts, they filed cross-motions for summary judgment. The Superior Court ruled
for petitioner, explaining that under Maine's statute:
"Denial
of a tax exemption is explicitly and primarily triggered by engaging in a
certain level of interstate commerce. This denial makes operation of the
institutions serving non-residents more expensive. This increased cost results
from an impermissible distinction between in-state and out-of-state
consumers. See Commonwealth Edison Co., 453 U. S., at 617-19
.... Maine's charitable tax exemption is denied, not because there is a
difference between the activities of charitable institutions serving residents
and non-residents, but because of the residency of the people whom the
institutions serve." App. to Pet. for Cert. 14a-15a (footnote omitted).
The Town,
but not the State, appealed and the Maine Supreme Judicial Court reversed. 655
A. 2d 876 (1995). Noting that a Maine statute6 characterized tax
exemptions as "tax expenditures," it viewed the exemption for
charitable institutions as the equivalent of a purchase of their
services. Id., at 878. Because the exemption statute
"treats all Maine charities alike"-given the fact that "all have
the opportunity to qualify for an exemption by choosing to dispense the majority of their charity locally"-it
"regulates evenhandedly with only incidental effects on interstate
commerce." Id., at 879. In the absence of evidence that
petitioner's camp "competes with other summer camps
outside of or within Maine," or that the statute "impedes interstate
travel" or that it "provides services that are necessary for interstate
travel," the Court concluded that petitioner had not met its heavy burden
of persuasion that the statute is unconstitutional." Ibid.
We granted
certiorari. 516 U. S. 1157. For the reasons that
follow, we now reverse.
II
During the first years of our
history as an independent confederation, the National Government lacked the
power to regulate commerce among the States. Because each State was free to
adopt measures fostering its own local interests without regard to possible
prejudice to nonresidents, what Justice Johnson characterized as a
"conflict of commercial regulations, destructive to the harmony of the
States," ensued. See Gibbons v. Ogden, 9 Wheat. 1, 224 (1824) (opinion
concurring in judgment). In his view, this "was the immediate cause that
led to the forming of a [constitutional] convention." Ibid. "If there was anyone object
riding over every other in the adoption of the constitution, it was to keep the
commercial intercourse among the States free from all invidious and partial
restraints." Id., at 231.7
We
have subsequently endorsed Justice Johnson's appraisal of the central
importance of federal control over interstate and foreign commerce and, more
narrowly, his conclusion that the Commerce Clause had not only granted Congress
express authority to override restrictive and conflicting commercial
regulations adopted by the States, but that it also had immediately effected a
curtailment of state power. "In short, the Commerce Clause even without
implementing legislation by Congress is a limitation upon the power of the
States. Southern Pacific Co. v. Arizona ex rel. Sullivan, 325 U.S. 761
[(1945)]; Morgan v. Virginia, 328 U.S. 373[(1946)]." Freeman v. Hewit, 329 U.S. 249, 252 (1946). Our decisions on this
point reflect "upon fullest consideration, the course of adjudication
unbroken through the Nation's history." Ibid. See also H. P. Hood &
Sons, Inc. v. Du Mond, 336 U.S. 525, 534-535
(1949). Although Congress unquestionably has the power to repudiate or
substantially modify that course of adjudication,8 it has not done
so.
This
case involves an issue that we have not previously addressed—the disparate real
estate tax treatment of a nonprofit service provider based on the residence of
the consumers that it serves. The Town argues that our dormant Commerce Clause
jurisprudence is wholly inapplicable to this case, because interstate commerce
is not implicated here and Congress has no power to
enact a tax on real estate. We first reject these arguments, and then explain
why we think our prior cases make it clear that if profit making enterprises
were at issue, Maine could not tax petitioner more heavily than other camp
operators simply because its campers come principally from other States. We
next address the novel question whether a different rule should apply to a
discriminatory tax exemption for charitable and benevolent institutions.
Finally, we reject the Town's argument that the exemption should either be
viewed as a permissible subsidy or as a purchase of services by the State
acting as a "market participant."
III
We are
unpersuaded by the Town's argument that the dormant Commerce Clause is
inapplicable here, either because campers are not "articles of
commerce," or more generally because the camp's "product is delivered
and `consumed' entirely within Maine." Brief for Respondents 17-18. Even
though petitioner's camp does not make a profit, it is unquestionably engaged
in commerce, not only as a purchaser, see Katzenbach
v. McClung, 379 U.S. 294, 300-301 (1964); United States v. Lopez, 514 U. S. ___, ___ (1995) (slip op., at
10), but also as a provider of goods and services. It markets those services,
together with an opportunity to enjoy the natural beauty of an inland lake in
Maine, to campers who are attracted to its facility from all parts of the
Nation. The record reflects that petitioner "advertises for campers in
[out of state] periodicals . . . and sends its Executive Director annually on
camper recruiting trips across the country." App. 49-50. Petitioner's
efforts are quite successful; 95 percent of its campers come from out of State.
The attendance of these campers necessarily generates the transportation of
persons across state lines that has long been recognized as a form of
"commerce." Edwards v.
California, 314 U.S. 160, 172 (1941); see also Caminetti v. United States, 242 U.S. 470, 491 (1917); Hoke v. United States, 227 U.S. 308, 320 (1913).
Summer
camps are comparable to hotels that offer their guests goods and services that
are consumed locally. In Heart of Atlanta
Motel, Inc. v. United States, 379 U.S. 241 (1964), we recognized that
interstate commerce is substantially affected by the activities of a hotel that
"solicits patronage from outside the State of Georgia through various
national advertising media, including magazines of national circulation."
Id., at 243. In that case, we held that commerce was substantially affected by
private race discrimination that limited access to the hotel and thereby
impeded interstate commerce in the form of travel. Id., at 244, 258; see Lopez, 514 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at
10-11). Official discrimination that limits the access of nonresidents to
summer camps creates a similar impediment. Even when business activities are
purely local, if "`it is interstate commerce that feels the pinch, it does
not matter how local the operation which applies the squeeze.' " Heart of Atlanta, 379 U.S., at 258
(quoting United States v. Women's
Sportswear Mfrs. Assn., 336 U.S. 460, 464 (1949)).
Although
Heart of Atlanta involved Congress'
affirmative Commerce Clause powers, its reasoning is applicable here. As we
stated in Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441
U.S. 322 (1979), "The definition of `commerce' is the same when relied on
to strike down or restrict state legislation as when relied on to support some
exertion of federal control or regulation." Id., at 326, n. 2. That case
in turn rested upon our reasoning in Philadelphia
v. New Jersey, 437 U.S. 617 (1978), in which we rejected a "two-tiered
definition of commerce." Id., at 622. "Just as Congress ha[d] power
to regulate the interstate movement of [the] wastes" at issue in that
case, so too we held were States "not free from constitutional scrutiny
when they restrict that movement." Id., at 622-623. See also Sporhase v. Nebraska ex rel.Douglas, 458 U.S. 941, 953 (1982).
The
Town's arguments that the dormant Commerce Clause is inapplicable to petitioner
because the campers are not "articles of commerce," or more generally
that interstate commerce is not at issue here, are therefore unpersuasive. The
services that petitioner provides to its principally out of state campers
clearly have a substantial effect on commerce, as do state restrictions on
making those services available to nonresidents. Cf. C & A Carbone, Inc. v. Clarkstown,
511 U.S. 383, 391 (1994).
The Town
also argues that the dormant Commerce Clause is inapplicable because a real
estate tax is at issue. We disagree. A tax on real estate, like any other tax,
may impermissibly burden interstate commerce. We may assume as the Town argues
(though the question is not before us) that Congress could not impose a
national real estate tax. It does not follow that the States may impose real
estate taxes in a manner that discriminates against interstate commerce. A
State's "power to lay and collect taxes, comprehensive and necessary as
that power is, cannot be exerted in a way which involves a discrimination
against [interstate] commerce." Pennsylvania
v. West Virginia, 262 U.S. 553, 596 (1923).
To allow
a State to avoid the strictures of the dormant Commerce Clause by the simple
device of labeling its discriminatory tax a levy on real estate would destroy
the barrier against protectionism that the Constitution provides. We noted in West Lynn Creamery Corp. v. Healy, 512
U.S. 186 (1994), that "[t]he paradigmatic . . . law discriminating against
interstate commerce is the protective [import] tariff or customs duty, which
taxes goods imported from other States, but does not tax similar products produced in State." Id., at 193. Such tariffs are
"so patently unconstitutional that our cases reveal not a single attempt
by a State to enact one." Ibid. Yet, were the Town's theory adopted, a
State could create just such a tariff with ease. The State would need only to
pass a statute imposing a special real estate tax on property used to store,
process, or sell imported goods. By gearing the increased tax to the value of
the imported goods at issue, the State could create the functional equivalent
of an import tariff. As this example demonstrates, to accept the Town's theory
would have radical and unacceptable results.
We
therefore turn to the question whether our prior cases preclude a State from
imposing a higher tax on a camp that serves principally nonresidents than on
one that limits its services primarily to residents.
IV
There is
no question that were this statute targeted at profit making entities, it would
violate the dormant Commerce Clause. "State laws discriminating against
interstate commerce on their face are `virtually per se invalid.' " Fulton
Corp. v. Faulkner, 516 U. S. ___, ___ (1996) (slip op., at 5) (quoting Oregon
Waste Systems, Inc. v. Department of Environmental Quality of Ore., 511 U.S. 93
(1994)). It is not necessary to look beyond the text of this statute to
determine that it discriminates against interstate commerce. The Maine law
expressly distinguishes between entities that serve a principally interstate
clientele and those that primarily serve an intrastate market, singling out
camps that serve mostly in staters for beneficial tax
treatment, and penalizing those camps that do a principally interstate
business. As a practical matter, the statute encourages affected entities to
limit their out of state clientele, and penalizes the principally nonresident
customers of businesses catering to a primarily interstate market.
If such a
policy were implemented by a statutory prohibition against providing camp
services to nonresidents, the statute would almost certainly be invalid. We
have "consistently . . . held that the Commerce Clause . . . precludes a
state from mandating that its residents be given a preferred right of access,
over out of state consumers, to natural resources located within its borders or
to the products derived therefrom." New
England Power Co. v. New Hampshire, 455 U.S. 331, 338 (1982). Our authorities
on this point date to the early part of the century.9 Petitioner's
"product" is in part the natural beauty of Maine itself, and in
addition the special services that the camp provides. In this way, the Maine
statute is like a law that burdens out of state access to domestically
generated hydroelectric power, New
England Power, or to local landfills, Philadelphia
v. New Jersey, 437 U.S. 617 (1978). In those cases, as in this case, the
burden fell on out of state access both to a natural resource, and to related
services provided by state residents.10
Avoiding
this sort of "economic Balkanization," Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441 U.S. 322, 325 (1979), and the retaliatory
acts of other States that may follow, is one of the central purposes of our negative
Commerce Clause jurisprudence. See ibid.; West
v. Kansas Natural Gas Co., 221 U.S. 229, 255 (1911) (expressing concern
that "embargo may be retaliated by embargo, and commerce will be halted at
state lines"). And, as we noted in Brown-Forman
Distillers Corp. v. New York State Liquor Authority, 476 U.S. 573, 580
(1986): "Economic protectionism is not limited to attempts to convey
advantages on local merchants; it may include attempts to give local consumers
an advantage over consumers in other States."11 By encouraging
economic isolationism, prohibitions on out of state access to in state
resources serve the very evil that the dormant Commerce Clause was designed to
prevent.
* * *
We
recognize that the Town might have attempted to defend the Maine law under the per se rule by demonstrating that it
" `advances a legitimate local purpose that cannot be adequately served by
reasonable nondiscriminatory alternatives.' " Id., at 101 (quoting New Energy Co., 486 U.S., at 278 ). In assessing respondents' arguments, we would have
applied our "strictest scrutiny." Hughes
v. Oklahoma, 441 U.S. 322, 337 (1979). This is an extremely difficult
burden, "so heavy that `facial discrimination by itself may be a fatal
defect.' " Oregon Waste, 511
U.S., at 101 (quoting Hughes, 441
U.S., at 337 ); see Chemical Waste Management, Inc. v. Hunt, 504 U.S. 334, 342 (1992)
("Once a state tax is found to discriminate against out of state commerce,
it is typically struck down without further inquiry"). Perhaps realizing
the weight of its burden, the Town has made no effort to defend the statute
under the per se rule, and so we do
not address this question. See Fulton
Corp. v. Faulkner, 516 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 7-8). 16 We
have no doubt that if petitioner's camp were a profit-making entity, the
discriminatory tax exemption would be impermissible.
V
The
unresolved question presented by this case is whether a different rule should
apply to tax exemptions for charitable and benevolent institutions. Though we
have never had cause to address the issue directly, the applicability of the
dormant Commerce Clause to the nonprofit sector of the economy follows from our
prior decisions.
* * *
. . .
Protectionism, whether targeted at for-profit entities or serving, as here, to
encourage nonprofits to keep their efforts close to home, is forbidden under
the dormant Commerce Clause.19 If there is need for a special
exception for nonprofits, Congress not only has the power to create it,20
but also is in a far better position than we to determine its dimensions.21
* * *
VII
As was
true in Bacchus Imports, Ltd. v. Dias,
the facts of this particular case, viewed in
isolation, do not appear to pose any threat to the health of the national
economy. Nevertheless, history, including the history of commercial conflict
that preceded the constitutional convention as well as the uniform course of
Commerce Clause jurisprudence animated and enlightened by that early history,
provides the context in which each individual controversy must be judged. The
history of our Commerce Clause jurisprudence has shown that even the smallest
scale discrimination can interfere with the project of our federal Union. As
Justice Cardozo recognized, to countenance discrimination of the sort that
Maine's statute represents would invite significant inroads on our
"national solidarity":
"The
Constitution was framed under the dominion of a political philosophy less
parochial in range. It was framed upon the theory that the peoples of the
several states must sink or swim together, and that in the long run prosperity
and salvation are in union and not division." Baldwin v. G. A. F. Seelig, Inc., 294 U.S. 511, 523 (1935).
The judgment of the Maine Supreme
Judicial Court is reversed.
It is so ordered.
JUSTICE SCALIA, with whom THE CHIEF
JUSTICE, JUSTICE THOMAS, and JUSTICE GINSBURG join, dissenting.
The
Court's negative commerce clause jurisprudence has drifted far from its
moorings. Originally designed to create a national market for commercial
activity, it is today invoked to prevent a State from giving a tax break to
charities that benefit the State's inhabitants. In my view, Maine's tax
exemption, which excuses from taxation only that property used to relieve the
State of its burden of caring for its residents, survives even our most
demanding commerce clause scrutiny.
We have
often said that the purpose of our negative commerce clause jurisprudence is to
create a national market. As Justice Jackson once observed, the "vision of
the Founders" was "that every farmer and every craftsman shall be
encouraged to produce by the certainty that he will have free access to every
market in the Nation, that no home embargoes will withhold his exports, and no
foreign state will by customs duties or regulations exclude them." H. P. Hood & Sons, Inc. v. Du Mond, 336 U.S. 525, 539 (1949). In our zeal to advance
this policy, however, we must take care not to overstep our mandate, for the
Commerce Clause was not intended "to cut the States off from legislating
on all subjects relating to the health, life, and safety of their citizens,
though the legislation might indirectly affect the commerce of the
country." Huron Portland Cement Co.
v. Detroit, 362 U.S. 440, 443-444 (1960).
Our cases
have struggled (to put it nicely) to develop a set of rules by which we may
preserve a national market without needlessly intruding upon the States' police
powers, each exercise of which no doubt has some effect on the commerce of the
Nation. See Oklahoma Tax Comm'n v.
Jefferson Lines, Inc., 514 U.S. 175, 180 -183 (1995). The rules that we
currently use can be simply stated, if not simply applied: Where a State law
facially discriminates against interstate commerce, we observe what has
sometimes been referred to as a "virtually per se rule of
invalidity;" where, on the other hand, a state law is nondiscriminatory,
but nonetheless adversely affects interstate commerce, we employ a deferential
"balancing test," under which the law will be sustained unless
"the burden imposed on [interstate] commerce is clearly excessive in
relation to the putative local benefits," Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 142 (1970). See Oregon Waste Systems, Inc. v. Department
of Environmental Quality of Ore., 511 U.S. 93, 99 (1994).
While the
"virtually per se rule of invalidity" entails application of the
"strictest scrutiny," Hughes v.
Oklahoma, 441 U.S. 322, 337 (1979), it does not necessarily result in the
invalidation of facially discriminatory State legislation, see, e.g., Maine v. Taylor, 477 U.S. 131 (1986)
(upholding absolute ban on the importation of baitfish into Maine), for
"what may appear to be a `discriminatory' provision in the
constitutionally prohibited sense--that is, a protectionist enactment--may on
closer analysis not be so," New
Energy Co. of Ind. v. Limbach, 486 U.S. 269, 278 (1988). Thus, even a
statute that erects an absolute barrier to the movement of goods across state
lines will be upheld if "the discrimination is demonstrably justified by a
valid factor unrelated to economic protectionism," id., at 274, or to put
a finer point on it, if the State law "advances a legitimate local purpose
that cannot be adequately served by reasonable nondiscriminatory
alternatives," id., at 278.
In
addition to laws that employ suspect means as a necessary expedient to the
advancement of legitimate State ends, we have also preserved from judicial
invalidation laws that confer advantages upon the State's residents but do so
without regulating interstate commerce. We have therefore excepted the State
from scrutiny when it participates in markets rather than regulates them--by
selling cement, for example, see Reeves,
Inc. v. Stake, 447 U.S. 429 (1980), or purchasing auto hulks, see Hughes v. Alexandria Scrap Corp., 426
U.S. 794 (1976), or hiring contractors, see White
v. Massachusetts Council of Construction Employees, 460 U.S. 204 (1983).
Likewise, we have said that direct subsidies to domestic industry do not run
afoul of the Commerce Clause. See New
Energy Co., 486 U.S., at 278. In sum, we have declared that "[t]he
Commerce Clause does not prohibit all state action designed to give its
residents an advantage in the marketplace, but only action of that description in connection with the State's regulation of interstate
commerce." Ibid. (emphasis in original).
In
applying the foregoing principles to the case before us, it is of course
important to understand the precise scope of the exemption created by Me. Rev.
Stat. Ann., Tit. 36, §652(1)(A) (Supp. 1996-1997). . .
.
JUSTICE THOMAS, with whom JUSTICE
SCALIA joins, and with whom THE CHIEF JUSTICE joins as to Part I, dissenting.
The tax at
issue here is a tax on real estate, the quintessential asset that does not move
in interstate commerce. Maine exempts from its otherwise generally applicable
property tax, and thereby subsidizes, certain charitable organizations that
provide the bulk of their charity to Maine's own residents. By invalidating
Maine's tax assessment on the real property of charitable organizations primarily
serving non-Maine residents, because of the tax's alleged indirect effect on
interstate commerce, the majority has essentially created a "dormant"
Necessary and Proper Clause to supplement the "dormant" Commerce
Clause. This move works a significant, unwarranted, and, in my view,
improvident expansion in our "dormant," or "negative,"
Commerce Clause jurisprudence.1 For that reason, I join JUSTICE
SCALIA'S dissenting opinion.
I write
separately, however, because I believe that the improper expansion undertaken
today is possible only because our negative Commerce Clause jurisprudence,
developed primarily to invalidate discriminatory state taxation of interstate
commerce, was already both overbroad and unnecessary. It was overbroad because,
unmoored from any constitutional text, it brought within the supervisory
authority of the federal courts state action far afield from the discriminatory
taxes it was primarily designed to check. It was unnecessary because the
Constitution would seem to provide an express check on the States' power to
levy certain discriminatory taxes on the commerce of other States-not in the
judicially created negative Commerce Clause, but in the Art. I, § 10,
Import-Export Clause, our decision in Woodruff
v. Parham, 8 Wall. 123 (1869), notwithstanding. That the expansion effected
by today's decision finds some support in the morass of our negative Commerce
Clause case law only serves to highlight the need to abandon that failed
jurisprudence and to consider restoring the original Import Export Clause check
on discriminatory state taxation to what appears to be its proper role. As I
explain in Part III, the tax (and tax exemption) at issue in this case seems
easily to survive Import-Export Clause scrutiny; I would therefore, in all likelihood, sustain Maine's tax under that Clause as
well, were we to apply it instead of the judicially created negative Commerce
Clause.
I
The
negative Commerce Clause has no basis in the text of the Constitution, makes
little sense, and has proved virtually unworkable in application. See, e. g., Tyler Pipe Industries, Inc. v. Washington
State Dept. of Revenue, 483 U. S. 232, 259-265 (1987) (SCALIA, J.,
dissenting); Bendix Autolite
Corp. v. Midwesco Enterprises, Inc., 486 U. S.
888, 895-898 (1988) (SCALIA, J., concurring in judgment). In one fashion or
another, every Member of the current Court2 and a goodly number of
our predecessors3 have at least recognized these problems, if not
been troubled by them.4 Because the expansion effected by today's
holding further undermines the delicate balance in what we have termed
"Our Federalism," Younger v.
Harris, 401 U.S. 37, 44 (1971), I think it worth revisiting the underlying
justifications for our involvement in the negative aspects of the Commerce
Clause, and the compelling arguments demonstrating why those justifications are
illusory.
To cover
its exercise of judicial power in an area for which there is no textual basis,
the Court has historically offered two different theories in support of its
negative Commerce Clause jurisprudence. The first theory posited was that the
Commerce Clause itself constituted an exclusive grant of power to Congress.
See, e.g., Passenger Cases, 7 How.
283, 393-400 (1849).5 The "exclusivity" rationale was likely
wrong from the outset, however. See, e.g., The
Federalist No. 32, p. 154 (M. Beloff ed. 1987)
(A. Hamilton) ("[N]otwithstanding the
affirmative grants of general authorities, there has been the most pointed care
in those cases where it was deemed improper that the like authorities should
reside in the states, to insert negative clauses prohibiting the exercise of
them by the states").6 It was seriously questioned even in
early cases. See License Cases,5
How. 504, 583, 615, 618, 624 (1847) (Four, and arguably five, of the seven
participating Justices contending that the Commerce Clause was not exclusive).
And, in any event, the Court has long since "repudiated" the notion
that the Commerce Clause operates as an exclusive grant of power to Congress,
and thereby forecloses state action respecting interstate commerce. Freeman v. Hewit,
329 U.S. 249, 259, 262 (1946) (Rutledge, J., concurring); see also, e.g., Southern Pacific Co. v. Arizona ex rel.
Sullivan, 325 U.S. 761, 766 -767 (1945) ("Ever since Willson v. Black Bird Creek Marsh Co., 2 Pet.
245, and Cooley v. Board of Wardens,
12 How. 299, it has been recognized that, in the absence of conflicting
legislation by Congress, there is a residuum of power in the state to make laws
governing matters of local concern which nevertheless in some measure affect
interstate commerce or even, to some extent, regulate it"); James v. Watt, 716 F. 2d 71, 73 (CA1
1983) (Breyer, J.) (noting that "the strong Madison/Marshall `preemptive'
view of the Interstate Commerce Clause is no longer the law of the land"),
cert. denied, 467 U.S. 1209 (1984).7
Indeed,
the Court's early view that the Commerce Clause, on its own, prohibited state
impediments to interstate commerce such that "Congress cannot re grant, or
in any manner reconvey to the states that
power," Cooley v. Board of Wardens
of Port of Philadelphia ex rel. Soc. for Relief of Distressed Pilots, 12
How. 299, 318 (1852), quickly proved untenable. Compare Pennsylvania v. Wheeling & Belmont Bridge Co., 13 How. 518
(1852) (holding that construction of the Wheeling Bridge impeded commerce in
violation of the Commerce Clause), with Pennsylvania
v. Wheeling & Belmont Bridge Co., 18 How. 421, 426 (1856) (upholding
Federal Act that declared the Wheeling Bridge to be "[a] lawful structur[e]"); see also Transportation Co. v. Parkersburg, 107 U.S. 691, 701 (1883)
("It is Congress, and not the Judicial Department, to which the
Constitution has given the power to regulate commerce").8 And,
as this Court's definition of the scope of congressional authority under the
positive Commerce Clause has expanded, the exclusivity rationale has moved from
untenable to absurd.
The second
theory offered to justify creation of a negative Commerce Clause is that
Congress, by its silence, pre-empts state legislation. See Robbins v. Shelby County Taxing Dist., 120 U.S. 489, 493 (1887)
(asserting that congressional silence evidences congressional intent that there
be no state regulation of commerce). In other words, we presumed that
congressional "inaction" was "equivalent to a declaration that
inter State commerce shall be free and untrammelled."
Welton v. Missouri, 91 U.S. 275, 282
(1876). To the extent that the "preemption by silence" rationale ever
made sense, it too has long since been rejected by this Court in virtually
every analogous area of the law.
For
example, ever since the watershed case of Erie
R. Co. v. Tompkins, 304 U.S. 64 (1938), this Court has rejected the notion
that it can create a federal common law to fill in great silences left by Congress,
and thereby pre-empt state law. We have recognized that "a federal court
could not generally apply a federal rule of decision, despite the existence of
jurisdiction, in the absence of an applicable Act of Congress." Milwaukee v. Illinois, 451 U.S. 304, 313
(1981).9
The
limited areas in which we have created federal common law typically involve
either uniquely federal issues or the rights and responsibilities of the United
States or its agents. See Texas
Industries, Inc. v. Radcliff Materials, Inc., 451 U.S. 630, 641 (1981). But
where a federal rule is not essential, or where state law already operates
within a particular field, we have applied state law
rather than opting to create federal common law. See United States v. Kimbell Foods, Inc., 440 U.S. 715, 730 (1979)
(rejecting "generalized pleas for uniformity" as a basis for creating
federal common law); see also Atherton v.
FDIC, 519 U. S. 213 (1997) (slip op., at 12) (same).
Similarly,
even where Congress has legislated in an area subject to its authority, our
pre-emption jurisprudence explicitly rejects the notion that mere congressional
silence on a particular issue may be read as
pre-empting state law:
"As
is always the case in our pre-emption jurisprudence, where `federal law is said
to bar state action in fields of traditional state regulation . . . we have
worked on the "assumption that the historic police powers of the States
were not to be superseded by the Federal Act unless that was the clear and
manifest purpose of Congress." ' " California Div. of Labor Standards Enforcement v. Dillingham Constr. N.
A., Inc., 519 U. S. 316 (1997) (slip op., at 8) (citations omitted).
See also, Jones v. Rath
Packing Co., 430 U.S. 519 (1977) (same); Rice v. Santa Fe Elevator Corp., 331 U.S. 218 (1947) (same).
To be
sure, we have overcome our reluctance to pre-empt state law in two types of
situations: (1) where a state law directly conflicts with a federal law; and
(2) where Congress, through extensive legislation, can be said to have
pre-empted the field. See Gade v. National Solid
Wastes Management Assn., 505 U.S. 88, 98 (1992). But those two forms of
pre-emption provide little aid to defenders of the negative Commerce Clause.
Conflict pre-emption only applies when there is a direct clash between an Act
of Congress and a state statute, but the very premise of the negative Commerce
Clause is the absence of congressional action.
Field
pre-emption likewise is of little use in areas where Congress has failed to
enter the field, and certainly does not support the general proposition of
"preemption by silence" that is used to provide a veneer of
legitimacy to our negative Commerce Clause forays. Furthermore, field
pre-emption is itself suspect, at least as applied in the absence of a congressional
command that a particular field be pre-empted. Perhaps
recognizing this problem, our recent cases have frequently rejected field
pre-emption in the absence of statutory language expressly requiring it. See,
e.g., O'Melveny & Myers v. FDIC,
512 U.S. 79, 85 (1994) ("Nor would we adopt a court made rule to
supplement federal statutory regulation that is comprehensive and detailed;
matters left unaddressed in such a scheme are presumably left subject to the
disposition provided by state law"). Even when an express pre=emption
provision has been enacted by Congress, we have narrowly defined the area to be
pre-empted. See, e.g., Dillingham, supra,
at ___ (slip op., at 7-8); Cipollone v. Liggett
Group, Inc., 505 U.S. 504, 517 (1992).
In the
analogous context of statutory construction, we have similarly refused to rely
on congressional inaction to alter the proper construction of a pre existing statute. See Central Bank of Denver, N. A. v. First
Interstate Bank of Denver, N. A., 511 U.S. 164, 180 -185 (1994). And, even
more troubling, the "preemption by silence" rationale virtually
amounts to legislation by default, in apparent violation of the constitutional
requirements of bi-cameralism and presentment. Cf. INS v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 919, 951 -959
(1983). Thus, even were we wrongly to assume that congressional silence
evidenced a desire to pre-empt some undefined category of state laws, and an
intent to delegate such policy laden categorization to the courts, treating
unenacted congressional intent as if it were law would be constitutionally
dubious.
In sum,
neither of the Court's proffered theoretical justifications—exclusivity or
preemption by silence—currently supports our negative Commerce Clause
jurisprudence, if either ever did. Despite the collapse of its theoretical foundation,
I suspect we have nonetheless adhered to the negative Commerce Clause because
we believed it necessary to check state measures contrary to the perceived
spirit, if not the actual letter, of the Constitution. Thus, in one of our
early uses of the negative Commerce Clause, we invalidated a state tax on the
privilege of selling goods "which are not the growth, produce, or
manufacture of the State." Welton v.
Missouri, 91 U.S. 275, 278 (1876). And in Cook v. Pennsylvania, 97 U.S. 566 (1878), we struck down a state
tax on out of state goods sold at auction. See also, e.g., I. M. Darnell & Son Co. v. Memphis, 208 U.S. 113 (1908); Voight v. Wright, 141 U.S. 62 (1891); Walling v. Michigan, 116 U.S. 446
(1886); Webber v. Virginia, 103 U.S.
344 (1881). To this day, we find discriminatory state taxes on out of state
goods to be "virtually per se
invalid" under our negative Commerce Clause. See, e.g., West Lynn Creamery, Inc. v. Healy, 512
U.S. 186 (1994); Associated Industries of
Mo. v. Lohman, 511 U.S. 641 (1994); New
Energy Co. of Ind. v. Limbach, 486 U.S. 269 (1988); Maryland v. Louisiana, 451 U.S. 725 (1981). Though each of these
cases reached what intuitively seemed to be a desirable result—and in some
cases arguably was the constitutionally correct result, as I describe below—the
negative Commerce Clause rationale upon which they rested remains unsettling
because of that rationale's lack of a textual basis.
Moreover,
our negative Commerce Clause jurisprudence has taken us well beyond the
invalidation of obviously discriminatory taxes on interstate commerce. We have
used the Clause to make policy laden judgments that we are ill equipped and
arguably unauthorized to make. See Moorman
Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U.S. 267, 278 -280 (1978) (recognizing that
establishing a formula for apportioning taxes on multistate corporations would
require "extensive judicial lawmaking" for which the courts are ill
suited). In so doing, we have developed multifactor tests in
order to assess the perceived "effect" any particular state
tax or regulation has on interstate commerce. See Complete Auto Transit, Inc. v. Brady, 430 U.S. 274 (1977); see also
Quill Corp. v. North Dakota, 504 U.S.
298 (1992). And in an unabashedly legislative manner, we have balanced that
"effect" against the perceived interests of the taxing or regulating
State, as the very description of our "general rule" indicates:
"Where
the statute regulates even handedly to effectuate a legitimate local public interest,
and itseffects on interstate commerce are only
incidental, it will be upheld unless the burden imposed on such commerce is
clearly excessive in relation to the putative local benefits. Huron Portland Cement Co. v. Detroit,
362 U.S. 440 (1960). If a legitimate local purpose is found, then the question
becomes one of degree. And the extent of the burden that will be tolerated will
of course depend on the nature of the local interest involved, and on whether
it could be promoted as well with a lesser impact on interstate
activities." Pike v. Bruce Church,
Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 142 (1970)
Any test
that requires us to assess (1) whether a particular statute serves a
"legitimate" local public interest; (2) whether the effects of the
statute on interstate commerce are merely "incidental" or
"clearly excessive in relation to the putative benefits"; (3) the
"nature" of the local interest; and (4) whether there are alternative
means of furthering the local interest that have a "lesser impact" on
interstate commerce, and even then makes the question "one of
degree," surely invites us, if not compels us, to function more as
legislators than as judges. See Bendix Autolite Corp. v. Midwesco
Enterprises, Inc., 486 U.S., at 897 -898 (Scalia, J., concurring in
judgment) (urging abandonment of the Pike
balancing test so as to "leave essentially
legislative judgments to the Congress").
Moreover,
our open ended balancing tests in this area have allowed us to reach different
results based merely "on differing assessments of the force of competing
analogies." Oklahoma Tax Comm'n v.
Jefferson Lines, Inc., 514 U.S. 175, 197, n. 7 (1995). The examples are
almost too numerous to count, but there is perhaps none that more clearly makes
the point than a comparison of our decisions in Philadelphia v. New Jersey, 437 U.S. 617 (1978), and its progeny,
on the one hand, and Bowman v. Chicago
& Northwestern R. Co., 125 U.S. 465 (1888), and its progeny, on the
other. In Bowman, we recognized that
States can prohibit the importation of "cattle or meat or other provisions
that are diseased or decayed, or otherwise, from their condition and quality,
unfit for human use or consumption," id., at 489, a view to which we have
adhered for more than a century, see, e.g., Maine
v. Taylor, 477 U.S. 131 (1986); Asbell
v. Kansas, 209 U.S. 251 (1908). In Philadelphia,
however, we held that New Jersey could not prohibit the importation of
"solid or liquid waste which originated or was collected outside the
territorial limits of the State." 437 U.S., at 618 (internal quotation
marks omitted). The cases were arguably distinguishable, but only on policy
grounds and not on any distinction derived from the text of the Constitution
itself.
Similarly,
we have in some cases rejected attempts by a State to limit use of the State's
own natural resources to that State's residents. See, e.g., Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441 U.S. 322, 338
(1979). But in other cases, we have upheld just such preferential access. See,
e.g., Sporhase v. Nebraska ex rel. Douglas, 458 U.S.
941, 955 -957 (1982); cf. Baldwin v. Fish
and Game Comm'n of Mont., 436 U.S. 371 (1978). Again, the distinctions
turned on often subtle policy judgments, not the text of the Constitution.
In my
view, none of this policy laden decision-making is proper. Rather, the Court
should confine itself to interpreting the text of the Constitution, which
itself seems to prohibit in plain terms certain of the more egregious state
taxes on interstate commerce described above, see supra, at ,
and leaves to Congress the policy choices necessary for any further regulation
of interstate commerce.
II
Article I,
§10, cl. 2 of the Constitution provides that "[n]o State shall, without
the Consent of the Congress, lay any Imposts or Duties on Imports or Exports . . . ." To the 20th century reader, the
Clause appears only to prohibit States from levying certain kinds of taxes on
goods imported from or exported to foreign nations. But a strong argument can
be made that for the Constitution's Framers and ratifiers—representatives
of States which still viewed themselves as semi-independent sovereigns—the
terms "imports" and "exports" encompassed not just trade
with foreign nations, but trade with other States as well.
The late
Professor William Crosskey, in a persuasive treatment
of this subject nearly a half century ago, unearthed numerous Founding era
examples in which the word "import" referred to goods produced in
other States. See W. Crosskey, “The True Meaning of
the Imports and Exports Clause: Herein of ‘Interstate Trade Barriers’ in 1787,”
1 Politics and the Constitution in the
History of the United States 295-323 (1953). Crosskey
recounts, for example, that merchants frequently published advertisements in
the local newspapers announcing recent shipments of such "imported"
goods as "Philadelphia Flour," "Carolina Rice," and
"Connecticut Beef." Id., at 298.10 Similarly, the word
"export" was used to refer to goods shipped both to other States and
abroad. One writer, for example, urged his fellow Connecticut citizens to
manufacture stockings in sufficient quantity not only for the supply of
Connecticut "but for exportation to other States" as well. Letter
from "A. C.," The Massachusetts
Centinel, Sept. 5, 1787, p. 1, col. 1 (reprinted
from New Haven Gazette) (emphasis
added). Another argued that Connecticut could enrich itself "[b]y making
and refining Cyder for exportation with which we might supply the Southern
States, as well as the large provinces of Quebec and Nova Scotia." The
Connecticut Farmer, New Haven Gazette,
Oct. 6, 1785, p. 2, col. 3 (second and third emphases added).
More
significantly, the early statute books are replete with examples of these
commonplace 18th century understandings of the terms "import" and
"export." The Virginia cheese duty Act of October 1786, for example,
provided for a duty of "three pence a pound on all cheese . . . imported
into this commonwealth." 12 Hening, Virginia
Statutes at Large, ch. 29, §2, p. 289 (emphasis
added). As complaints published in New England newspapers indicate, that duty
was imposed on cheese produced by the New England States. See The Salem [Mass.] Mercury, Mar. 3, 1787, p. 2, col. 2. Moreover, the duty was but
one of many imposed by Virginia, which had for some time, it seems,
"imposed like duties upon the importation of New England rum, Lynn [Mass.]
Shoes, Cheese, Cordage, and a variety of other articles manufactured in the
Eastern States." The Independent
Chronicle [Boston], Apr. 19, 1787, p. 3, col. 2; see 11 Hening,
Virginia Statutes at Large, ch. 8, §8, pp. 121-122
(Oct. 1782) (imposing a tonnage duty "on all vessels . . . from or to
foreign parts, or from or to any of the United States," and an impost duty on goods "imported or brought into this
commonwealth . . . from any port or place whatsoever").
Maryland,
for its part, taxed certain "articles exported out of" the State,
including flour shipped to New England. 1784 Md. Laws, ch.
84, §1; see also Letter from "A Citizen," The Norwich [Conn.] Packet,
Jan. 17, 1788, p. 1, col. 1 ("The New England States have imported, for
four years past, from the State of Maryland, upwards of twenty-five thousand
barrels of flour annually--on which they have been obliged to pay a duty for
the liberty of exportation"). And, when it provided for the inspection of
salted foods "exported and imported from and to the town of
Baltimore," Maryland expressly included salted foods "brought or
imported into the said town, from any part of this state, or any one of the
United States, or from any foreign port whatever." 1786 Md. Laws, ch. 17, §5.
In similar
fashion, Connecticut adopted an excise tax that distinguished between
"imported Chocolate," taxed at three pence per pound, and
"Chocolate made within this State," taxed at one Penny per pound.
1783 Conn. Acts and Laws 619. And in May 1784, Connecticut adopted an import
duty that expressly applied to certain enumerated articles "imported or
brought into this State, by Land or Water, from any of the United States of
America." 1784 Conn. Acts and Laws 271.11
In fact,
when state legislators of the founding generation intended to limit the term
"imports" only to goods of foreign origin, they were quite adept at
so indicating. See 1784 Conn. Acts and Laws 269 (provision regarding merchants
"who shall import annually into [New London or New Haven] from Europe,
Asia or Africa, Goods, Wares and Merchandise, the Growth, Produce or
Manufacture of said Countries"); id., at 270 (setting duties for
"Goods imported into this State from any Foreign Port, Island or
Plantation not within any of The United States"); 2 New York Laws, ch. 7, p. 12 (1886) (Act of Nov. 18, 1784, setting duties
for certain "articles imported from Europe"). Thus, based on this
common 18th century usage of the words "import" and
"export," and the lack of any textual indication that the Clause was
intended to apply exclusively to foreign goods, it seems likely that those who
drafted the Constitution sought, through the Import Export Clause, to prohibit
States from levying duties and imposts on goods imported from or exported to
other States as well as foreign nations, and that those who ratified the
Constitution would have so understood the Clause.
Our Civil
War era decision in Woodruff v. Parham,
8 Wall. 123 (1869), of course, held that the Import Export Clause applied only
to foreign trade. None of the parties to these proceedings have challenged that
holding, but given that the common 18th century understanding of the words used
in the Clause extended to interstate as well as foreign trade, it is worth
assessing the Woodruff Court's reasoning with an eye toward reconsidering that
decision in an appropriate case.
The Woodruff Court began with a textual
argument, contending that the power to levy "imposts" given to
Congress in Art. I, §8, cl. 1 applied only to foreign imports.
Such a limited reading of the word "imposts" in that Clause was
necessary, the Court claimed, because any other reading would be nonsensical:
Goods "imported" by one State from another State, explained the
Court, would be an "export" of the State where the goods were
produced or grown, and the supposed power given to Congress in Art. I, §8 to
levy an "impost" on such "imports" would be prohibited by
the Art. I, §9 provision that "[n]o Tax or Duty shall be laid on Articles
exported from any State." This apparent tension between §8 and §9 led the
Court to believe that the word "imposts" in §8 must be read as
applying only to foreign imports in order to avoid a
partial negation of the Art. I, §8 power. The Court then extrapolated from this
reading that the word "impost" in Art. I, §10 similarly had the same
limited application to foreign imports. As we have
already seen, however, see supra, at , the word
"import" derived its meaning from the jurisdiction into which goods
were imported; consequently, it does not necessarily follow that the imports on
which Congress was given the power to lay "imposts" in Art. I, §8
were identical to the imports and exports on which the several States were
prohibited from levying-Imposts or Duties" by Art. I, §10.12
The Woodruff Court bolstered its textual
argument with two further arguments, neither of which appear still to be valid,
if ever they were: First, that in the history of the Constitution's formation
and adoption, "the words imports and imposts were used with exclusive
reference to articles imported from foreign countries," id., at 133
(emphasis added), and second, the policy concern that goods imported from other
States would be forever exempt from tax if the Clause were read to apply to
interstate imports.
As to the
first non-textual argument, the Woodruff
Court was selective in its use of history, to say the least. It first asserted
that, in Articles VI and IX of the Articles of Confederation, the words
"imports, exports, and imposts are used with exclusive reference to
foreign trade, because [those articles] have regard only to the treaty making
power of the federation." Id., at 134. Even if the Woodruff Court's assertion was accurate as to Articles VI and IX,
which is doubtful,13 Article IV cannot be so read. That Article
expressly permitted "duties" and "impositions" to be levied
on property removed from one State to another, as long as
the property was not owned by "the United States, or either of them."14
The Woodruff Court next turned to the use of
the words "duty" and "import" in the Continental Congress.
The Court noted that the Continental Congress recommended that the States give
it permission to levy a duty of five percent on all "foreign merchandise
imported into the country," and that, though "imperfectly . . .
preserved," the debates in the Congress "are full of the subject of
the injustice done by the States who had good seaports, by duties levied in
those ports on foreign goods designed for States who had no such ports."
Id., at 134.
There is,
of course, no question that the ability of seaport States to tax the foreign imports of their neighbors was a source of discord
between the States, and continued to be so through the Constitutional
Convention itself. In order to support its contention,
however, the Woodruff Court was
obligated to show not merely that the words "duty,"
"impost," and "imports" were used in reference to foreign
goods, but that foreign goods were the exclusive reference. Contrary to the
Woodruff Court's claim, the historical record does not appear to support such
an exclusive use of the words.
The
records of the Continental Congress contain numerous examples of the words
"duty," "impost," and "import" being used with
reference to interstate trade. In 1785, for example, in response to the
increasing animosities between the states engendered by conflicting interstate
trade regulations, an amendment to the Articles of Confederation was proposed
that would have vested in the Continental Congress the power to lay "such
imposts and duties upon imports and exports, as may be necessary for the
purpose" of "regulating the trade of the States, as well with foreign
Nations, as with each other." 28 Journals
of the Continental Congress, Mar. 28, 1785, p. 201 (1933) (emphasis added).
Two provisos within the proposed amendment further suggest that interstate
imports and exports were very much within the purview of the amendment: First,
“that the Citizens of the States shall in no instance be subjected to pay
higher imposts and duties, than those imposed on the subjects of foreign powers";
and second, “that the Legislative power of the several States shall not be
restrained from prohibiting the importation or exportation of any species of
goods or commodities whatsoever." Ibid.
As early
as 1779, the problems posed by interstate trade barriers had become acute
enough to warrant a request by the Continental Congress urging the States
"to repeal all laws or other restrictions laid on the inland trade between
the said states." Resolution of Aug. 25, 1779, 14 Journals of the Continental Congress 986; id., at 996 (adopting
resolution). While this particular resolution does not
use the words "duties" or "imports," it seems evident from
a survey of the statutory "duties" being levied by some States on
goods "imported" from other States, see supra, at ", that the resolution was directed at just such
duties on imports from other States.
Many of
the States ignored the request, of course, and their "rival, conflicting
and angry regulations," continued to be a source of conflict until the new
Constitution went into effect. See Madison, Preface
to Debates in the Convention of 1787 (Draft), circa 1836, in 3 Farrand 547; see also, e.g., William Ellery to Samuel Dick,
Aug. 2, 1784, in 7 Letters of Members of
the Continental Congress 579 (E. Burnett ed., 1934) (hereinafter Burnett's
Letters) (predicting that Rhode Island would not agree to the national impost
requested by the Congress in 1781 "until the States shall have agreed not
to lay any duties upon goods imported into them from any one of their Sister States;
perhaps not then") (emphasis added); William Samuel Johnson to Jonathan
Sturges (draft), Jan. 26, 1785, in 8 Burnett's Letters 13 (noting that the
Continental Congress was considering asking the States "to invest Congress
with the Power of regulating their Trade as well with foreign Nations as with
each other," a move which "might probably overturn the System [of
"duties" on "imported" goods, see supra,at
] Conn[ecticu]t has adopt'd
as relat[iv]e to N Y which it is said she will
counteract by regulat[ion]s of her Assembly now
convening") (emphasis in original).
In fact,
the animosity engendered by the various duties levied on imports from other
States was one of the motivating factors leading to the Annapolis Convention of
1786. See T. Powell, Vagaries and Varieties
in Constitutional Interpretation 182 ("When the Framers spoke in 1787,
the states were substantially sovereign, and their exercises of sovereign
powers in adversely affecting trade from sister states was one of the factors
leading to the Annapolis conference"). As noted by Tench
Coxe, one of the Pennsylvania Commissioners appointed
to attend the Convention, "Goods of the growth product and manufacture of
the Other States in Union were [in several of the States] charged with high
Duties upon importation into the enacting State--as great in many instances as
those imposed on foreign Articles of the same Kinds." Coxe,
Letter to the Virginia Commissioners at Annapolis, Sept. 13, 1786, reprinted in
9 The Papers of James Madison 125
(Rutland ed. 1975). Coxe thought the very purpose of
the Annapolis Convention had been "[t]o procure
an alteration" of this and other practices, which were, he added,
"evidently opposed to the great principles and Spirit of the Union."
Ibid.
Similarly,
one of the first criticisms leveled against the Articles of Confederation
during the ensuing Federal Convention was the general Government's inability to
prevent "quarrels between states," including those arising from the
various "duties" the States imposed upon each other, both on foreign
goods moving through the seaport States and on each other's goods. See 1 Farrand 19, 25 (Edmund Randolph, May 29); see also Madison,
Preface to Debates in the Convention of 1787 (draft), circa 1836, in 3 Farrand 547-548 ("Some of the States, as Connecticut,
taxed imports as from Massts higher than imports even
from G. B. of w[hi]ch Massts.
complained to Virga. and doubtless to other States").
While the
focus of the Convention quickly moved beyond the mere abolition of trade
barriers, of course, there are passages in the available Convention debates
which indicate that interstate trade barriers remained a concern, and that the
words of the Import Export Clause applied to interstate as well as to foreign
trade. George Mason, for example, proposed to exempt from the Import Export
Clause prohibition duties necessary for the States' execution of their
inspection laws. Otherwise, he argued, the "restriction on the States
would prevent the incidental duties necessary for the inspection & safe keeping
of their produce, and be ruinous to the [Southern] Staple States." 2 Farrand 588 (Sept. 12). James Madison seconded the motion,
and his comment that any feared abuse of the power to levy duties on exports
for inspection purposes was perhaps best guarded against by "the right in
the Genl. Government to regulate trade between State & State," id., at
588-589 (emphasis added), strongly suggests that exports to other States were
within the Clause's reach. 15
These
references to duties on interstate imports and exports are bolstered by several
more in the ratification debates. See, e.g., 2 J. Elliot, Debates on the Federal Constitution 57-58 (2d ed. 1891) (Dawes,
Massachusetts ratifying convention) ("As to commerce, it is well known that
the different states now pursue different systems of duties in
regard to each other. By this, and for want of general laws of
prohibition through the Union, we have not secured even our own domestic
traffic that passes from state to state") (original emphasis deleted).
Indeed, one of the principal Anti Federalist complaints against the new
Constitution was that States were prohibited from laying any duties or imposts
on imports or exports, a prohibition that, in their view, left only direct
taxation as a means for the States to support their own governments. See, e.g.,
Brutus 1, Oct. 18, 1787, in 13 The
Documentary History of the Ratification of the Constitution 415 (J.
Kaminsky & G. Saladino eds. 1981) (Doc. Hist.)
("No state can . . . lay any duties, or imposts, on imports, or exports .
. . [T]he only mean therefore left, for any state to
support its government and discharge its debts, is by direct taxation").16
This complaint overstates the case somewhat--States could still levy excises,
and duties other than those on imports and exports. See, e.g., The Federalist No. 32, p. 151 (M. Beloff ed. 1987) (A. Hamilton) ("([W]ith the sole exception of duties on imports and exports)[, States] would, under the plan of the convention,
retain [the] authority [to raise theirown revenues]
in the most absolute and unqualified sense"). But it does suggest that the
Anti Federalists, at least, viewed the Import Export Clause as prohibiting all
other state taxes, including the duties then in place on goods imported from neighboring
States. And moves in various States shortly after the Constitution's
ratification to repeal the offending duties on interstate trade support the
Anti Federalist view. Compare An Act repealing the Laws made for levying and
collecting a Duty on Articles imported into this State, 1789 Conn. Acts and
Laws 377 (Jan. 1789), with, e.g., An Act for levying and collecting Duties on
the Importation of certain Articles, and for appropriating the same, 1784 Conn.
Acts and Laws 309 (Oct. 1784) (providing for, inter alia, a duty of three pence
"on each Pound of Sugar . . . whether the Produce or Manufacture of the
United States, or not, imported into this State").
Justice
Nelson, of course, pointed out in his Woodruff
dissent that a lack of "security or protection" against
"obstructions and interruptions of commerce among the States" was
"one of the principal grievances that led to the Convention of 1787, and
to the adoption of the Federal Constitution." Woodruff, 8 Wall., at 140-141. But he seems not to have had in his
arsenal many of the historical materials cited above, which indicate that the
words used in the Import Export Clause encompassed, at the time the
Constitution was written, both interstate and foreign trade.17
Indeed, the Woodruff majority itself felt
compelled to note that its "research [had] extended" only so far as
permitted by "the discussions on this subject, as they have come down to
us from that time." Id., at 136; see also id., at 134 (referring to the
"imperfectly . . . preserved" discussions of the Continental
Congress). Whatever the cause, the Woodruff
Court's analysis of the historical usage of the words overlooked many contrary
examples and is thus not especially compelling.
The second
contention that the Woodruff Court
used to bolster its textual argument was a policy concern based on an
unnecessarily broad view of the Import Export Clause's prohibition. The Woodruff Court believed that the
prohibition on "Duties or Imposts on Exports or Imports" exempted
imported articles, and the merchants who traded in them, from state taxation of
any kind, at least so long as they remained in their original packages. Id., at
137. This view of the Clause's prohibition would result in "the grossest
injustice," said the Court, were the Clause to be read as applying to
"articles brought from one State into another," for "[n]either
the State nor the city which protects [the import merchant's] life and property
[could] make him contribute a dollar to support its government." Ibid.
Woodruff's
broad reading of the Clause's prohibition was explicitly adopted three years
later in Low v. Austin, 13 Wall. 29
(1872), a case involving foreign imports. But we
expressly overruled Low 20 years ago,
in Michelin Tire Corp. v. Wages, 423
U.S. 276, 279 (1976), holding that the Import Export Clause "cannot be
read to accord imported goods preferential treatment that permits escape from
uniform taxes imposed without regard to foreign origin for services which the
State supplies," id., at 287; cf. United
States v. International Business Machines Corp., 517 U. S. ___, ___ (1996)
(slip op., at 14-16) (distinguishing Art. I, §9, cl. 5 Export Clause, which
bars the United States from imposing any tax on exports, from the Import Export
Clause, which prohibits States from levying only duties and imposts). While Michelin and Low dealt with foreign imports, the
expansive interpretation of the Import Export Clause's prohibition rejected by
Michelin was the same interpretation that gave the Woodruff Court pause and
that seems to have been an impetus to its refusal to read the Clause as
applying to imports from other States. Thus, after Michelin, the second
argument the Woodruff Court used to bolster its weak textual analysis—that it
would be a gross injustice to prohibit States from levying any taxes on goods
which were produced in other States—no longer has any force.
There is
nothing else of consequence to support the Woodruff Court's holding. The only
remaining argument made by the Woodruff majority was that it was
"improbable" that the Convention would have permitted States to tax
"imports" from other States merely with the assent of Congress,
because the revenues that would accrue to Congress by granting such assent
would prove too great a temptation for Congress to serve as a neutral arbiter
regarding such taxes. Woodruff, supra,
at 133. The Woodruff Court's
speculation was without historical support, however, and pales in comparison to
the substantial evidence described above regarding the meaning of the words in
the Clause, see supra, at 621-624.18
In short,
there is little in the Woodruff
opinion to sustain its holding, and its weakness is even more evident given the
contrary precedent rejected by the Woodruff
Court. In Brown v. Maryland, 12
Wheat. 419, 449 (1827), Chief Justice Marshall, writing for the Court,
suggested: "[W]e suppose the principles laid down in this case [namely,
that a State license tax on importers of foreign articles was invalid both
under the Import Export Clause and the act of Congress which authorizes importation]
to apply equally to importations from a sister State." And just eight
years before Woodruff, Chief Justice
Taney, writing for a unanimous Court, struck down a stamp tax on bills of
lading for gold being shipped from California to New York, holding that
"the State tax in question is a duty upon the export of gold and silver,
and consequently repugnant to the [Import Export] clause in the
Constitution." Almy v. California, 24 How. 169, 175 (1861)
(emphasis added).
Chief
Justice Marshall's statement in Brown
was merely dicta, of course, but the Woodruff
majority's rejection of the precedential force of Almy, based solely on its
assertion that "[i]t seems to have escaped the
attention of counsel on both sides, and of the Chief Justice who delivered the
opinion, that the case was one of inter-state commerce," 8 Wall., at 137,
is harder to sustain. The Almy Court expressly noted that Mr. Almy
was charged with failing to pay the stamp tax on a bill of lading for "a
quantity of gold dust for transportation to New York" from San Francisco,
24 How., at 172, and the explicit "question presented by the case"
was whether a State had a right "to tax such instruments when used in
commerce among the States," Brief for Plaintiff in Error in Almy v. California, D. T. 1860, No. 23, pp.
1-2 (emphasis added); see also id., at 3 (referring to fact that the tax was on
bills of lading "for exports to other States"). Woodruff's rejection of Brown
and Almy—precedent
which better reflected the historical record and common usage of the Clause's
words—was thus highly questionable.
In sum, it would seem that Woodruff
was, in all likelihood, wrongly decided. Of course, much of what the Import
Export Clause appears to have been designed to protect against has since been
addressed under the negative Commerce Clause. As the majority recognizes,
discriminatory State taxation of interstate commerce is one of the core pieces
of our negative Commerce Clause jurisprudence. Ante, at 16. Were it simply a matter of invalidating state laws
under one clause of the Constitution rather than another, I might be inclined
to leave well enough alone. Indeed, our rule that state taxes that discriminate
against interstate commerce are virtually per se invalid under the negative
Commerce Clause may well approximate the apparent prohibition of the Import
Export Clause itself. But, as already described, without the proper textual
roots, our negative Commerce Clause has gone far afield of its core--and we
have yet to articulate either a coherent rationale for permitting the courts
effectively to legislate in this field, or a workable test for assessing which
state laws pass negative Commerce Clause muster. Precedent as unworkable as our
negative Commerce Clause jurisprudence has become is simply not entitled to the
weight of stare decisis. See Holder v.
Hall, 512 U.S. 874, 936-937 (1994) (Thomas, J., concurring in judgment).
And it is quite possible that, were we to revisit Woodruff, we might find that the Constitution already affords us a
textual mechanism with which to address the more egregious of State actions
discriminating against interstate commerce.
III
Were we
thus to shed ourselves of our non-textual negative Commerce Clause and all the
accompanying multi factor balancing tests we have employed, and instead merely
apply what appears to me to be the relevant provision of the Constitution, this
would seem to be a fairly straightforward case
(although I reserve final judgment of the matter for a case when the Import
Export Clause is specifically addressed by the parties). Unlike the Export
Clause of Art. I, §9, which prohibits the Congress from levying any tax on
exports, the Import Export Clause only prohibits States from levying
"duties" and "imposts." See International Business Machines, 517 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at
14-15).
The Maine
property tax at issue here is almost certainly not an impost, for, as 18th
century usage of the word indicates, an impost was a tax levied on goods at the
time of importation. See, e.g., The Observer
No. XII, The Connecticut Courant and
Weekly Intelligencer, Jan. 7, 1790, p. 1, col. 2 ("[I]mpost is a tax on merchandize, payable at the port of
entry");19 N. Bailey, An
Universal Etymological English Dictionary (26 ed. 1789) (defining
"impost" as "a tax or tribute, but more especially such as is
received by a prince or state, for goods brought into any haven from other
nations");20 Michelin,
supra, at 287 ("[I]mposts and duties . . .
are essentially taxes on the commercial privilege of bringing goods into a
country"). Because the tax at issue here is levied on real
property—property that cannot possibly have been "imported"—the tax
would not seem to fit within any of the commonly accepted definitions of
"impost."
"Duty,"
however, though frequently used like "impost" to denote "money
paid for custom of goods," An
Universal Etymological English Dictionary, supra, does not appear to have
been limited to taxes assessed at portside. See, e.g., S. Johnson, A Dictionary of the English Language
(7th ed. 1785) ("Duty . . . Tax; impost; custom; toll. All the wines make
their way through several duties and taxes, before they reach the port")
(second emphasis added); 2 Elliot 331 (John Williams, New York ratifying
convention) (noting that Congress' Art. I, §8 power "extend[s] to duties
on all kinds of goods, to tonnage and poundage of vessels, to duties on written
instruments, newspapers, almanacs, &c"). In fact, "imposts"
seems to have been viewed as a particular subclass of
duties; the fact that the two words are used disjunctively in the Import Export
Clause suggests, therefore, that something broader than portside customs was
within the constitutional prohibition.
Because of
the somewhat ambiguous usage of the words "duty" and
"impost," Luther Martin inquired of their meaning during the
Convention. James Wilson, a member of the Committee on Detail, replied as
follows: "[D]uties are applicable to many
objects to which the word imposts does not relate. The
latter are appropriated to commerce; the former extend to a variety of objects,
as stamp duties &c." 2 Farrand 305 (emphasis
in original); see also 2 Storing 54 (Luther Martin, in Maryland Convention,
describing same colloquy); The Fallacies of the Freeman Detected by a Farmer,
Freeman's Journal, April 1788, in 3 Storing 186-187 ("Under the term
duties [in Art. I, §8], every species of indirect taxes is included, but it
especially means the power of levying money upon printed books, and written
instruments"). What seems likely from these descriptions is that a duty,
though broader than an impost, was still a tax on particular
goods or written instruments.
It is
important to note, moreover, that the Martin Wilson colloquy is in reference to the Art. I, §8 power given to Congress to
levy duties. That power is broader than the prohibition on States found in Art.
I, §10, which reaches not all duties, but only those on "imports or
exports."21 But even without this additional limitation, one
kind of tax that duties almost certainly did not encompass were
"direct" taxes, such as property taxes and poll taxes. See, e.g., The Federalist No. 12 (A. Hamilton)
(distinguishing direct taxes, such as property taxes, from indirect taxes, such
as imposts, duties, and excises); Freeman's
Journal, in 3 Storing, supra, 186-187 ("Under the term duties [in Art.
I, §8], every species of indirect taxes is included"); see also Michelin, 423 U.S., at 286 , 290-291.
The tax at
issue here is nothing more than a tax on real property. Such taxes were
classified as "direct" taxes at the time of the Framing, and were not
within the class of "indirect" taxes encompassed by the common
understanding of the word "duties." The amount of the Maine tax is
tied to the value of the real property on which it is imposed, not to any particular goods, and not even to the number of campers
served. It does not appear, therefore, to be a "duty" on
"imports" in any sense of the words.22 Even when coupled
with the tax exemption for certain Maine charities (which is, in truth, no
different than a subsidy paid out of the State's general revenues), Maine's
property tax would not seem to be a "Duty or Impost on Imports or
Exports" within the meaning of the Import Export Clause. Thus, were we to
overrule Woodruff and apply the
Import Export Clause to this case, I would in all likelihood
sustain this tax under that Clause as well.
Footnotes to Court’s Opinion
1 Most of
petitioner's tax bill was for real estate taxes. See, e. g., App.
43 (petitioner paid 1991 real estate taxes of $20,770.71 and personal property
taxes of $994.70).
2 The
statute provides:
"The
following property of institutions and organizations is exempt from taxation:
"1.
Property of institutions and organizations.
"A.
The real estate and personal property owned and occupied or used solely for
their own purposes by benevolent and charitable institutions incorporated by
this State, and none of these may be deprived of the right of exemption by reason of the source from which its funds are derived or
by reason of limitation in the classes of persons for whose benefit such funds
are applied.
"(1)
Any such institution that is in fact conducted or operated principally for the
benefit of persons who are not residents of Maine is entitled to an exemption
not to exceed $50,000 of current just value only when the total amount of any
stipends or charges that it makes or takes during any tax year, as defined by
section 502, for its services, benefits or advantages divided by the total
number of persons receiving such services, benefits or advantages during the
same tax year does not result in an average rate in excess of $30 per week when
said weekly rate is computed by dividing the average yearly charge per person
by the total number of weeks in a tax year during which such institution is in
fact conducted or operated principally for the benefit of persons who are not
residents of Maine. No such institution that is in fact conducted or operated
principally for the benefit of persons who are not residents of Maine and makes
charges that result in an average weekly rate per person, as computed under
this subparagraph, in excess of $30 may be entitled to
tax exemption. This subparagraph does not apply to institutions incorporated as
nonprofit corporations for the sole purpose of conducting medical research.
"For
the purposes of this paragraph, 'benevolent and charitable institutions'
include, but are not limited to, nonprofit nursing homes and nonprofit boarding
homes and boarding care facilities licensed by the Department of Human Services
pursuant to Title 22, chapter 1665 or its successor, nonprofit community mental
health service facilities licensed by the Commissioner of Mental Health, Mental
Retardation, and Substance Abuse Services, pursuant to Title 34-B, chapter 3
and nonprofit child care centers incorporated by this State as benevolent and
charitable institutions. For the purposes of this paragraph, 'nonprofit' means
a facility exempt from taxation under Section 501(c)(3) of the Code .... "
Me. Rev. Stat. Ann., Tit. 36, § 652(1)(A) (Supp. 1996).
3
The statute's language reserving the property tax
exemption for those entities operated "principally for the benefit"
of Maine residents is not without ambiguity. The parties are
in agreement, however, that because petitioner's camp is attended almost
entirely by out-of-staters, it would not qualify for the exemption under any
reading of the language. See Brief for Petitioner 2; Brief for Respondents 2,
n. 3; Tr. of Oral Arg. 36. The courts below appear to have presumed the same,
and we of course accept their interpretation of state law.
4
Petitioner also argued below that the Maine statute violated the Equal
Protection Clauses of the United States and Maine Constitutions, and the
Privileges and Immunities Clause, Art. IV, § 2, of the Federal Constitution.
The Maine Supreme Judicial Court had already found the statute constitutional
under an equal protection analysis in a prior decision, and adhered to its
earlier view. See Green Acre Baha'i Institute v. Eliot, 159
Me. 395, 193 A. 2d 564 (1963); 655 A. 2d 876, 879-880 (1995). As for the
privileges and immunities claim, the Supreme Judicial Court found petitioner's
argument unavailing. Id., at 880. These claims are not before
us.
5
The Superior Court referred to all of the original
defendants as "Municipal Defendants" because the State of Maine
intervened to defend the constitutionality of its statute. App. to Pet. for
Cert. 9a. However, the State did not appeal the adverse decision of the
Superior Court and, therefore, is not a respondent in this Court. We shall use
the term "Town" to refer to the respondents collectively.
6 Me. Rev. Stat. Ann., Tit. 36, § 196 (1990).
7 See also West Lynn Creamery, Inc. v. Healy, 512 U.S. 186, 193
, n. 9 (1994) (noting that "[t]he `negative' aspect of the Commerce
Clause was considered the more important by the `father of the Constitution,'
James Madison"); Hughes v. Oklahoma,
441 U.S. 322, 325 -326 (1979); Hughes v.
Alexandria Scrap Corp., 426 U.S. 794, 807 , n. 16 (1976) (quoting W.
Rutledge, A Declaration of Legal Faith
25-26 (1947)).
8
See New York v. United States, 505
U.S. 144, 171 (1992); Quill Corp. v.
North Dakota, 504 U.S. 298, 318 (1992); Prudential
Ins. Co. v. Benjamin, 328 U.S. 408, 429-430, 434-435 (1946).
16 Justice
Scalia submits that we err by following our precedent in Fulton and declining
to address an argument that the Town itself did not think worthy of pressing. Post, at 8-9. But even if there were
reason to consider the State's compliance with the per se rule, the Town would
not prevail. In the single case Justice Scalia points to in which we found the
per se standard to have been met, Maine
v. Taylor, 477 U.S. 131 (1986), the State had no " `reasonable
nondiscriminatory alternatives,' " Oregon
Waste, 511 U.S., at 101 (quoting New
Energy Co., 486 U.S., at 278 ), to the action it
had taken. Absent a bar on the import of certain minnows, there was no way for
Maine to protect its natural environment from the hazard of parasites and
nonnative species that might have been accidentally introduced into the State's
waters. Taylor, 477 U.S., at 141 . In contrast, here Maine has ample alternatives short
of a facially discriminatory property tax exemption to achieve its apparent
goal of subsidizing the attendance of the State's children at summer camp. Maine
could, for example, achieve this end by offering direct financial support to
parents of resident children. Cf. Shapiro
v. Thompson, 394 U.S. 618 (1969). Though we have not had the occasion to
address the issue, it might also be permissible for the State to subsidize
Maine camps directly to the extent that they serve residents. See West Lynn Creamery, Inc. v. Healy, 512
U.S., at 199 , n. 15; New Energy Co. of Ind. v. Limbach, 486 U.S. 269, 278 (1988) (noting
that "[d]irect subsidization of domestic industry
does not ordinarily run afoul" of the Commerce Clause); Hughes v. Alexandria Scrap Corp., 426
U.S. 794, 816 (1976) (Stevens, J., concurring). While the Town does argue its
case under the less exacting analysis set forth in, e.g., Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 142 (1970), "this
lesser scrutiny is only available `where other [nondiscriminatory] legislative
objectives are credibly advanced and there is no patent discrimination against
interstate trade.' " Chemical Waste,
504 U.S., at 343 , n. 5 (quoting Philadelphia v. New Jersey, 437 U.S. 617, 624 (1978) (emphasis
added)). Because the Maine statute is facially discriminatory, the more
deferential standard is inapplicable. Contrary to Justice Scalia's suggestion,
this case is quite unlike General Motors
Corp. v. Tracy, 519 U. S. ___ (1997). There, the Court premised its holding
that the statute at issue was not facially discriminatory on the view that
sellers of "bundled" and "unbundled" natural gas were
principally competing in different markets. See id., at ___ (slip op., at 18,
21) ("dormant Commerce Clause protects markets and participants in
markets, not taxpayers as such"). While it may be true that "[d]isparate treatment constitutes discrimination only if the
objects of the disparate treatment are . . . similarly situated," post, at
7, there is no question that the statute at issue here is facially
discriminatory because it disparately treats identically situated Maine
nonprofit camps depending upon whether they favor in state, as opposed to out
of state, campers.
19 Contrary
to Justice Scalia's suggestion, nothing in our holding today "prevent[s] a
State from giving a tax break to charities that benefit the State's
inhabitants." Post, at 1. The
States are, of course, free to provide generally applicable nondiscriminatory
tax exemptions without running afoul of the dormant Commerce Clause.
20 See n. 8, supra.
21
We must admit to some puzzlement as to the force of the argument underlying
Justice Scalia's dissent. On the one hand, he suggests that a categorical
exemption of nonprofit activities from dormant Commerce Clause scrutiny would
be proper. Post, at 13-14. Yet at the same time, he makes a great effort to
characterize this statute as being so narrow that, whatever the appropriate
generally applicable rule, the dormant Commerce Clause ought not to apply here.
Post, at 4. As we have explained, the argument in favor of a categorical
exemption for nonprofits is unpersuasive, and we disagree with Justice Scalia's
characterization of this statute's effects. Accordingly, we reject his position
on either of these theories.
Footnotes to Justice Thomas’s
opinion
1 Although
the terms "dormant" and "negative" have often been used
interchangeably to describe our jurisprudence in this area, I believe "negative"
is the more appropriate term. See Oklahoma
Tax Comm'n v. Jefferson Lines, Inc., 514 U. S. 175, 200 (1995) (SCALIA, J.,
joined by THOMAS, J., concurring in judgment) ("[T]he 'negative Commerce
Clause' ... is 'negative' not only because it negates state regulation of
commerce, but also because it does not appear in the Constitution"). There
is, quite frankly, nothing "dormant" about our jurisprudence in this
area. See Eule, “Laying the Dormant Commerce Clause
to Rest,” 91 Yale L. J. 425, 425, n. 1 (1982).
2 See,
e.g., C & A Carbone, Inc. v. Clarkstown, 511 U.S.
383, 401 (1994) (O'Connor, J., concurring in judgment) ("The scope of the
dormant Commerce Clause is a judicial creation"); Quill Corp. v. North
Dakota, 504 U.S. 298, 309 (1992) (Stevens, J., writing for a unanimous Court)
(recognizing that the Commerce Clause "says nothing about the protection
of interstate commerce in the absence of any action by Congress"); Wyoming
v. Oklahoma, 502 U.S. 437, 461 -462 (1992) (Scalia, J., joined by Rehnquist, C.
J., and Thomas, J., dissenting) (describing the "negative Commerce Clause"
as "nontextual"); Kassel v. Consolidated
Freightways Corp. of Del., 450 U.S. 662, 706 (1981) (Rehnquist, J., dissenting)
("[T]he jurisprudence of the `negative side' of the Commerce Clause
remains hopelessly confused "); cf. U. S. Term Limits, Inc. v. Thornton, 514
U.S. 779, 797 , n. 12 (1995) (Stevens, J., joined by Kennedy, Souter, Ginsburg,
and Breyer, JJ.) ("[T]he Constitution is clearly silent on the subject of
state legislation that discriminates against interstate commerce").
3
See, e.g., Wardair Canada Inc. v. Florida Dept. of Revenue,
477 U.S. 1, 17 (1986) (Burger, C. J., concurring in part and concurring in
judgment) (referring to "the cloudy waters of this Court's `dormant
Commerce Clause' doctrine"); Philadelphia
v. New Jersey, 437 U.S. 617, 623 (1978) (Stewart, J.) ("The bounds of
[the restraints imposed by the Commerce Clause itself, in the absence of
federal legislation], appear nowhere in the words of the Commerce
Clause"); Northwestern States
Portland Cement Co. v. Minnesota, 358 U.S. 450, 457 , 458 (1959) (Clark,
J.) (internal quotation marks omitted) (referring to our negative Commerce
Clause jurisprudence as a "tangled underbrush" and a "quagmire"); H. P. Hood & Sons, Inc. v. Du Mond, 336 U.S. 525, 534 -535 (1949) (Jackson, J.) (describing
the negative Commerce Clause as filling in one of the "great silences of
the Constitution"); McCarroll v. Dixie Greyhound Lines, Inc., 309 U.S. 176,
189 , (1940) (Black, J., joined by Frankfurter and Douglas, JJ., dissenting)
(criticizing the negative Commerce Clause as arising out of "[s]pasmodic and unrelated instances of litigation [that]
cannot afford an adequate basis for the creation of integrated national
rules" that "Congress alone" is positioned to develop).
4
Scholarly commentary, too, has been critical of our negative Commerce Clause
jurisprudence. See D. Currie, The
Constitution in the Supreme Court: The First Hundred Years 1789-1888, p.
234 (1985) (describing the negative Commerce Clause as "arbitrary,
conclusory, and irreconcilable with the constitutional text"); see also,
e.g., L. Tribe, American Constitutional
Law 439 (2d ed. 1988) ("The Supreme Court's approach to commerce
clause issues . . . often appears to turn more on ad hoc reactions to
particular cases than on any consistent application of coherent
principles"); Redish & Nugent, "The
Dormant Commerce Clause and the Constitutional Balance of Federalism,"
1987 Duke L. J. 569, 573 ("[N]ot only is there no textual basis [for it], the dormant
Commerce Clause actually contradicts, and therefore directly undermines, the
Constitution's carefully established textual structure for allocating power
between federal and state sovereigns"); B. Gavit,
The Commerce Clause of the United States
Constitution 22 (1932) (noting that the Court has set "no conscious
standard" but has rather, "in an imperial way," decided whether
each particular state action presented to it "was or was not an invalid
regulation of interstate commerce").
5 See
also Mayor of New York v. Miln, 11 Pet. 102, 157-159 (1837) (Story, J.,
dissenting); Groves v. Slaughter, 15
Pet. 449, 504, 506-508 (1841) (McLean, J., concurring); Cooley v. Board of Wardens of Port of Philadelphia ex rel. Soc. for
Relief of Distressed Pilots, 12 How. 299 (1852) (adopting a partial
exclusivity rationale for dormant Commerce Clause cases).
6
See also F. Frankfurter, The Commerce
Clause Under Marshall, Taney and Waite 13 (1937) ("The conception that
the mere grant of the commerce power to Congress dislodged state power finds no
expression" in the records of the Philadelphia Convention nor the
discussions preceding ratification); id., at 17-19 (noting that Chief Justice
Marshall's discussion of the "exclusiveness" doctrine in Gibbons v. Ogden, 9 Wheat. 1, 197-209
(1824), "was logically irrelevant to [his] holding," and adding that
"[i]t was an audacious doctrine, which, one may
be sure, would hardly have been publicly avowed in support of the adoption of
the Constitution. Indeed, The Federalist in effect denied it, by assuring that
only express prohibitions in the Constitution limited the taxing power of the
states" (citing The Federalist
No. 32)).
7 The
majority's assertion that James Madison viewed what we
have termed the "negative" aspect of the Commerce Clause as more
significant than its positive aspects, see ante, at 6, n. 7, is based on a
letter written by Madison more than 40 years after the Convention, see 3 The Records of the Federal Convention of
1787, p. 478 (M. Farrand ed. 1911) (hereinafter Farrand) (reprinting letter from James Madison to J. C.
Cabell, Feb. 13, 1829). The majority's interpretation of the letter is
anachronistic. There is nothing in the letter to suggest that Madison had in
mind the "negative" Commerce Clause we have created which supposedly
operates of its own force to allow courts to invalidate state laws that effect
commerce. Rather, Madison's reference to the Clause as granting a
"power" strongly suggests that he was merely asserting that the
Convention designed the Clause more to enable "the General
Government," namely, Congress, to negate state laws impeding commerce
"rather than as a power to be used for the positive purposes of the
General Government." Ibid.
8
See also ante, at 6 ("Congress unquestionably has the power to repudiate
or substantially modify th[e] course of [our negative
Commerce Clause] adjudication"); Southern
Pacific Co. v. Arizona ex rel. Sullivan, 325 U.S. 761, 769 (1945) (Congress
has "undoubted" power to "permit the states to regulate the
commerce in a manner which would otherwise not be permissible").
9
See also, Atherton v. FDIC, 519 U. S.
213 (1997) (slip op., at 4) (rejecting the "judicial `creation' of a
special federal rule of decision" and noting that " `[w]hether latent federal power should be exercised to displace
state law is primarily a decision for Congress,' not the federal courts")
(citation omitted); O'Melveny & Myers
v. FDIC, 512 U.S. 79, 83 (1994) (rejecting, as "so plainly
wrong," the contention that federal common law governs application of
state causes of action brought by the FDIC as receiver for a federally insured
savings and loan); Milwaukee, 451
U.S., at 314 and 313, n. 7 ("Federal common law is a `necessary' expedient"
resorted to only when the Court is "compelled to consider federal
questions `which cannot be answered from federal statutes alone' ")
(citation omitted).
10
See also Gazette of the State of Georgia,
Oct. 11, 1787, p. 3, col. 3 ("Just imported . . . Superfine Philadelphia
flour"); Newport [R. I.] Mercury, June 12, 1784, p. 4, col. 2
("Just imported . . . Burlington [New Jersey] and Carolina, Pork, in
Barrels"); ibid. ("Just imported. . . best Philadelphia Flour");
The South Carolina Weekly Gazette,
Sept. 13, 1783, p. 3, col. 2 ("Just imported, In the Sloop Rosana, . .
.from Rhode Island, . . . Potatoes, Apples, Onions by the bunch and bushel,
Beats, Carrots, and good warranted Cheese"); Columbian Herald [Charleston, S. C.], Nov. 26, 1787, p. 4, col. 4
("Just imported, From Philadelphia, . . . Dr. Martin's Celebrated Medicine
for Cancers, Ulcers, Wens, Scurvies, Tetters,
Ringworms, &c."); Newport
Mercury, July 31, 1786, p. 2, col. 2 (complaining that "last year
upwards of 700,000 bushels of corn were imported into [South Carolina] from
North Carolina and Virginia"); Columbian
Herald, Feb. 14, 1785, p. 2,col. 4 (complaint about legislation pending in
Georgia—later adopted—taxing "all goods imported into the back part of
that state from South Carolina").
11 Some
commentators have argued that the phrase, "imported or brought,"
suggests that Connecticut lawmakers intended to distinguish between foreign
goods "imported" and other States' goods "brought" into the
State. This supposed distinction between "imported" and
"brought" is not consistent with the remainder of the statute,
however. For example, the second paragraph of the Act uses the phrase
"brought or imported into this State" when referring exclusively to
items "that are not the Growth, Produce, or Manufacture of the United
States." 1784 Conn. Acts and Laws 271. And conversely,
"imported" is used alone in contexts where it plainly covers goods produced
in other States. See, e.g., id., at 309 (setting duty for sugar, "whether
the Produce or Manufacture of the United States, or not, imported into this
State"); cf. 1786 Md. Laws, ch. 17, §6 (setting
standards for "all beef and pork barrels brought to, or imported into,
Baltimore town, from any part of this state"). The more plausible view,
therefore, is that the words "brought" and "imported" are
largely redundant and, to the extent they refer to different activities, the
distinction in the phrase is not between foreign goods "imported"
into Connecticut, on the one hand, and other States' goods "brought"
into Connecticut, on the other, but between goods of both kinds--domestic and
foreign--commercially "imported" in quantity and those
"brought" in limited quantities by individuals in their own baggage.
Compare 1784 Conn. Acts and Laws, at 272 (using the phrase "imported or
brought" when referring both to a ship's cargo and to the "Baggage of
Passengers"), with id., at 273 (using only the word "imported"
when referring solely to the ship's cargo).
12
Even assuming that the word "impost" in the
two Clauses applied to the same class of "imports," there is nothing
nonsensical in reading "impost" in Art. I, §8 as applicable to
interstate as well as foreigntrade. It is frequently
the case that a broad grant of power in one Clause is restricted by another
Clause. Moreover, a State could also import goods from a federal territory, and
the congressional power to lay an impost on such (non foreign) trade would not run afoul of the Art. I,
§9 prohibition.
13
Article VI, §3 merely provided that "No State shall lay any imposts or
duties, which may interfere with any stipulations in treaties, entered into by
the United States in Congress assembled." 1 Stat. 5. And Article IX
provided: "The United States, in Congress assembled, shall have the sole
and exclusive right and power of . . . entering into treaties and alliances,
provided that no treaty of commerce shall be made, whereby the legislative
power of the respective States shall be restrained from imposing such imposts
and duties on foreigners, as their own people are subjected to, or from
prohibiting the exportation or importation of any species of goods or
commodities whatsoever. . . ." 1 Stat. 6. As should be evident, neither
Article requires a reading of "impost" as applicable exclusively to foreign imports. The better reading is that when the States
levied imposts in their individual capacities, they could not interfere with
treaties enacted by the States in their collective capacity. In fact, the two
provisions, read together, suggest the existence of much broader classes of
"imposts," "imports," and "exports," and that
only the sub class of imposts interfering with foreign trade might be
prohibited. The absence of this very qualifier in the later enacted Import
Export Clause creates a negative inference that the unqualified constitutional
language covered more than did the limited prohibition in the Articles of Confederation.
14
Indeed, some New Englanders apparently believed that the Virginia duty on New
England cheese, see supra, at , was contrary to
Article IV's provision that "no imposition, duties or restriction, shall
be laid by any State, on the property of the United States, or either of
them." 1 Stat. 4. See The Salem [Mass.] Mercury, Mar. 3, 1787. The general view
of the Clause, however, and certainly the view of the several States that
imposed duties on interstate trade, see supra, at ", was that it applied
only to goods actually owned by the States, not to goods grown or manufactured
within them. See The Salem [Mass.] Mercury, Mar. 3, 1787 ("[T]he
proper construction of that part of the Articles of Confederation is, that no
state in the union shall lay a tax on publick
property imported therein--for, be it remembered, Congress were, at the time
the Confederation was formed, exporters of almost every necessary for carrying
on the war, & the clause alluded to was intended to prevent any individual
state from laying a duty on those necessary supplies"); see also 12 Hening, Virginia Statutes at Large, ch.
40, §3, pp. 304-305 (Oct. 1786) (distinguishing between articles "which
are the property of the United States, or either of them," and articles
"which shall be proved to be of the growth, produce or manufacture of the
State from which they shall be imported").
15
Furthermore, in response to concerns that the inspection exemption might be
used merely as a pretext for taxing neighboring States, see 2 Farrand 589, Mason's proposal was further amended to make
any such State inspection laws "subject to the revision and controul of Congress." Id., at 607, 624. The need for,
and existence of, this further limitation on the States' authority to tax
imports and exports suggests that the Commerce Clause power itself, referred to
by Madison, would not operate to limit the States of its own accord. Seesupra, at , n. .
16
See also John Quincy Adams to William Cranch, Oct.
14, 1787, in 14 Doc. Hist. 222 ("How will it be possible for each
particular State to pay its debts, when the power of laying imposts or duties,
on imports or exports, shall be taken from them—By direct taxes, it may be said");
George Lee Turberville to James Madison, Dec. 11,
1787, in id., at 407 ("Why shou'd the states be
prevented from raising a Revenue by Duties or Taxes--on their own Exports? Are
the states not bound down to direct Taxation for the support of their police
& government?"); A Federal Republican, A Review of the Constitution
Proposed by the Late Convention, Oct. 28, 1787, in 3 The Complete Anti Federalist 79 (H. Storing ed. 1981) (hereinafter
Storing) ("The [Import Export Clause] is reducing [the States] to the
necessity of laying direct taxes"); Vox Populi, Massachusetts Gazette, Oct. Nov. 1787,
in 4 Storing 47 ("Must we be confined to a dry tax on polls andestates . . . ?").
17 Farrand did not publish his volumes until 1911 (although
the Woodruff Court did have available
to it Madison's notes, as well as the more perfunctory convention journal); Burnetts' Letters were published between 1921 and 1936; the
Journals of the Continental Congress were published between 1904 and 1937;
volume 9 of The Papers of James Madison,
in which Tench Coxe's
letter was first reprinted, was not published until 1975; and a useful, readily
accessible collection of the various Anti Federalist writings was not available
until 1981. This is not to say that the original documents reprinted in these
volumes would not have been available to the Woodruff Court. But our ready access to, as well as our
appreciation of, such documents has increased over time.
18 Indeed,
were I similarly to speculate, I would not find it "improbable" that
the Convention would have trusted Congress to serve as a referee between
individual states. Since many states would necessarily be harmed by a single
state's impost, the institutional checks would in all
likelihood be sufficient to counter any revenue "temptation"
Congress might have faced, especially given the extensive revenue authority
granted directly to Congress in Art. I, §8, cl. 1. My "speculation"
is at least consistent with the recorded Convention debates. Roger Sherman
proposed the requirement that any revenues raised by congressionally approved
state imposts go into the federal treasury not as a separate means of raising
national revenues, but to insure that the states not
use a protectionist impost as a pretext for raising revenues from other states.
See 2 Farrand 441-442 (Aug. 28).
19
See also Providence Gazette and Country
Journal, Feb. 13, 1790,p. 1, col. 1 (reprinting
same); Gazette of the United States,
Jan. 9, 1790, p. 2, col. 1 (same).
20
See also T. Sheridan, A Complete
Dictionary of the English Language (6th ed. 1796) ("Impost . . . A
tax; a toll; custom paid"); S. Johnson, A Dictionary of the English Language (7th ed. 1785) ("Impost.
A tax; a toll; a custom paid. Taxes and imposts upon merchants do seldom good
to the king's revenue; for that that he wins in the hundred, he loseth in the shire. Bacon's Essays"); Barclay's
Universal English Dictionary 471 (B. Woodward rev. 1782) ("Impost. A toll;
custom paid for goods or merchandise"); T. Blount, A Law Dictionary (1670) ("Impost Tribute, Tallage,
or Custom; but more particularly it is that Tax which the King receives for
such merchandises as are imported into any Haven, from other Nations. . . . And it may be distinguished from Custom, which is
rather that profit which the King raises from Wares exported; but they are
sometimes confounded"); cf. 7 Oxford
English Dictionary 733 (2d ed. 1989) ("impost . . . A tax, duty,
imposition, tribute; spec. a customs duty levied on merchandise. Now chiefly Hist").
21 See,
e.g., DeWitt, Letter To the Free Citizens of the Commonwealth of Massachusetts,
American Herald, Boston, Oct. Dec.
1787, in 4 Storing 23 (noting that Congress "shall have the exclusive
power of imposts and the duties on imports and exports, [and, implicitly, a
concurrent] power of laying excises and other duties") (emphasis added);
Letters from The Federal Farmer, Oct. 10, 1787, in 2 Storing 239
(distinguishing between "impost duties, which
are laid on imported goods [and] may usually be collected in a few seaport
towns," and "internal taxes, [such] as poll and land taxes, excises,
duties on all written instruments, etc. [which] may fix themselves on every
person and species of property in the community"); Essays of Brutus, Dec.
13, 1787 in 2 Storing 392-393 (same); see also 2 Farrand
589 (noting that Morris "did not consider the dollar per Hhd laid on Tobo. in Virga. as a
duty on exportation, as no drawback would be allowed on Tobo.taken
out of the Warehouse for internal consumption").
22 Even
were I to agree with the majority that a particular property
tax may be a property tax in name only, see ante, at 9-10, and even were I to
assume that travel across state lines to consume services in another State
renders those traveling consumers "imports," it is difficult to
characterize the tax at issue here as a duty on imports. It is, rather, as the
majority recognizes, a "generally applicable state property tax."
Ante, at 1. Maine's grant of an exemption from the tax to some charitable
organizations that dispense their charity primarily to Maine residents makes
the tax something less than universal, but it does not make the tax, even in
practical effect, one that is levied exclusively, or even primarily, on
imports. See, e.g., New Energy Co. of
Ind. v. Limbach, 486 U.S. 269 (1988); Maryland
v. Louisiana, 451 U.S. 725, 756 (1981); License
Cases, 5 How. 504, 576 (1847); cf. Davis
v. Michigan Dept. of Treasury, 489 U.S. 803, 821 (1989) (Stevens, J.,
dissenting) (arguing, in an analogous context, that "the fact that a State
may elect to grant a preference, or an exemption, to a small percentage of its
residents does not make the tax discriminatory").