Part One: The Early Cases
After
deciding Gibbons v. Ogden in 1824,
Marshall wrote two more Commerce Clause opinions before Roger Taney replaced
him as Chief Justice in 1835. In both cases, no federal law had been enacted.
In Brown v. Maryland (1827) the court
dealt with a Maryland law that required importers of out-of-state goods to buy
a fifty dollar license to sell the goods in Maryland. The law was challenged as
a violation of the Commerce Clause and also as a violation of the Article I, Section
10, clause that prohibits states from laying “Imposts or Duties on Imports or
Exports.” Marshall found it violated both clauses.
In
considering the Commerce Clause issue, the Court alluded to, but never cited or
quoted, a federal law that permitted merchants to import and sell goods from
foreign countries. This allusion appears to be to a hypothetical federal law,
however, not to an actually existing law:
To what purpose should the power to
allow importation be given, unaccompanied with the power to authorize a sale of
the thing imported? Sale is the object of importation, and is an essential
ingredient of that intercourse, of which importation constitutes a part. . . .
Congress has a right, not only to authorize importation, but to authorize the imported
to sell.
The
Maryland law, said Marshall, impermissibly conflicted with the federal commerce
power by taxing the mere right to sell imported goods. Had Maryland simply
imposed a sales tax on the sale of the goods, it would have been within its
authority, but requiring a state license to sell imports—construed as a tax or
duty on the importer or the import business—impermissibly impinges on
Congress’s authority to regulate commerce. Thus,
even though the state law did not conflict with an existing federal law, the
state law was unconstitutional.
Marshall’s
opinion is particularly noteworthy for his recall of the need for national
commercial policies in 1787, a statement echoing Justice Johnson’s concurring
opinion in Gibbons:
The oppressed and degraded state of
commerce previous to the adoption of the constitution can scarcely be
forgotten. It was regulated by foreign nations with a single view to their own
interests; and our disunited efforts to counteract their restrictions were
rendered impotent by want of combination. Congress, indeed, possessed the power
of making treaties; but the inability of the federal government to enforce them
had become so apparent as to render that power in a great degree useless. Those
who felt the injury arising from this state of things, and those who were
capable of estimating the influence of commerce on the prosperity of nations,
perceived the necessity of giving the control over this important subject to a
single government. It may be doubted whether any of the evils proceeding from the
feebleness of the federal government, contributed more to that great revolution
which introduced the present system, than the deep and general conviction, that
commerce ought to be regulated by Congress. It is not, therefore,
matter of surprise, that the grant should be as extensive as the mischief, and
should comprehend all foreign commerce, and all commerce among the States. To
construe the power so as to impair its efficacy, would tend to defeat an
object, in the attainment of which the American public took, and justly took,
that strong interest which arose from a full conviction of its necessity.
(Emphasis added.)
Two
years later in Willson v. Black-Bird Creek Marsh Co. (1829),
however, the Court upheld the validity of a state law that authorized the
damming of a navigable creek, which was presumably under federal jurisdiction
because of its navigability. In his opinion, Marshall simply said, “We do not
think that the act empowering the Black Bird Creek Marsh Company to place a dam
across the creek, can, under all the circumstances of the case, be considered
as repugnant to the power to regulate commerce in its dormant state, or as being in conflict with any law passed on the
subject. There is no error, and the judgment is affirmed.” (Page 252; emphasis
added) Here is the first unambiguous reference to a “dormant” commerce
power—the federal power under the Commerce Clause that has not been exercised.
That is, here, like in Sturges
and Ogden, where the
constitutionality of state bankruptcy laws was challenged, there was no
conflicting federal regulation in effect. There could have been a federal law,
had Congress “awakened” its commerce power and used it; but Congress had not
used its power in any way relevant to this case, so the federal power was sleeping
or dormant.
The
Court’s upholding of the state law in Willson is also consistent with a rejection of the
exclusivity argument. If the power to regulate commerce were exclusively the
federal government’s power, then even if the federal government had not
exercised its Commerce Clause power (that is, even if it were dormant), the
states would be precluded from enacting any laws that do, in fact, regulate
commerce, such as Delaware did here. The Court articulated no clear exclusivity
rule; in fact, it did not apply a rule at all, unless the often used “totality
of the circumstances” rationale is deemed a rule, but courts often hide behind
the “totality of circumstances” language when they do not have apply a clear
principle or test to the issue they decide. Delaware’s law was upheld, unlike
the Maryland law in Brown, but it is
difficult to say why.
This
confusion over exclusivity continued into the years of the Roger Taney Court. A
state law requiring a license to sell imported liquor was upheld in the License
Cases (1847), but a state law to require aliens arriving in port to pay a tax
was struck down in the Passenger Cases (1849). In neither case were there any
relevant federal laws.
The
exclusivity argument raised by Daniel Webster in the Gibbons case and subsequently ignored in the Willson case and the License Cases,
but not in Brown and the Passenger Cases, was rejected once and
for all by the Roger Taney Court in Cooley
v. Board of Wardens of the City of Philadelphia (1852). In that case the
Court upheld a state law requiring all ships that sailed into Philadelphia
harbor to employ a local pilot. Philadelphia harbor is clearly on interstate
and international—that is, navigable—waters. Congress had passed a law in 1789
that left the regulation of local navigational rules to the states unless and
until Congress decided to regulate those matters. Thus, the case involved the
constitutionality of both the federal and the state statutes: could Congress
constitutionally delegate such regulation of navigation to the states?
In
a rule that came to be known as the doctrine of selective exclusivity or
selective
exclusiveness, the Court, by Justice Curtis, held that the federal
government had exclusive power to regulate activities that were inescapably
national in scope and that demanded a national scheme of regulation; in matters
of interstate or international commerce that did not require a national scheme
of regulation, the states were free to regulate as long as the federal government had not also acted to regulate the
matter:
Either absolutely to affirm or deny
that the nature of this power requires exclusive legislation by Congress is to
lose sight of the nature of the subjects of this power and to assert concerning
all of them what is really applicable but to a part. Whatever subjects of this
power are in their nature national, or admit only of one uniform system or plan
of regulation, may justly be said to be of such a nature as to require
exclusive legislation by Congress. That this cannot be affirmed of laws for the
regulation of pilots and pilotage is plain. [Cooley v. Board of Wardens, 53 U.S., at 319.]
If
the federal government had acted, however, its regulation would invalidate or
preempt the state regulations:
The act of 1789 contains a clear and
authoritative declaration by the first Congress that the nature of this subject
is such that, until Congress should find
it necessary to exert its power, it should be left to the legislation of
the states, that it is local and not national, that it is likely to be the best
provided for not by one system or plan of regulations, but by as many as the
legislative discretion of the several states should deem applicable to the
local peculiarities of the ports within their limits. [Cooley, id. Emphasis added.]
Was
it constitutional for Congress to give the states its constitutional power to regulate
commerce in this case?
Viewed in this light, so much of this
act of 1789 as declares that pilots shall continue to be regulated "by
such laws as the states may respectively hereafter enact for that
purpose," instead of being held to be inoperative as an attempt to confer
on the states a power to legislate of which the Constitution had deprived them,
is allowed an appropriate and important signification. [Cooley, id.]
Justice
McLean’s dissent digs into the question of the 1789 federal statute more deeply
than Curtis’s opinion does. From McLean’s nationalist perspective, the ability
of Congress to abdicate its responsibility to regulate commerce poses a problem
of state-federal relations under the Constitution that the majority’s rule does
not. The rule of selective exclusivity provided a relatively useful rubric for
deciding Dormant Commerce Clause cases into the twentieth century. But nothing
in constitutional law seems to last forever.
© William S Miller